Source: National Cancer Institute
The
world is getting too fat. In the United States obesity and overweight affect a
shocking 68% of people, of which half meet the criteria to be labeled obese. In
Belgium obesity levels are also becoming a problem, as both 41% of men and
women are ranked as overweight and/or obese (Eurostat, 2011).
One
of the reasons for this increase in the population’s waistline is the vast supply
of cheap foods that are high in fat and sugar content, and that not only
contribute to the obesity epidemic in Western countries but are also extending
it towards traditional and developing countries. A “fat forecast” based on a
statistical model by Finkelstein et al. (2012) predicts that by 2030 obesity
levels will have reached 51% in the United States. If we want to regain control
over obesity levels and its resulting health risks (e.g. heart disease and
diabetes), it is necessary to take serious measures.
A
few countries have chosen to combat the obesity epidemic by increasing the
price of fat foods or increasing taxes for overweight individuals. It is
assumed that this will discourage the consumption of fatty products and will
thereby promote healthier diets. Recently, a health economist from Ghent
University stated that it is time that Belgium introduces this so-called “fat
tax” (see article in De Standaard). According
to their study, raising the price of fat snacks, candy and drinks high in sugar
content by 10% should lead to a decrease in consumption of these products. Their
calculations show that over a period of 20 years, this would save €2,2 billion in
health care costs due to the expected reduction in costly diseases such as
diabetes, coronary heart disease and even some types of cancer.
A
healthier population and more money to spend on important health issues
such as developing cures for diseases caused by obesity. That sounds like a
perfect solution, doesn’t it?
Unfortunately
this view is a little too optimistic. Fiscal policies (such as taxes and
subsidies) are based on economic theory and are usually employed in order to
influence the supply and demand equilibrium. As a result, the effects these
policies have on human behavior have been underexposed. Raising the price of
consumer goods is in theory an effective way to lower demand for these
products (as shown by cigarette taxes), but it is unknown how well it would
work in practice as there are a lot of influences left out of consideration (i.e.
studies are usually based on predictive models rather than experimental or case
studies).
First
of all, research shows that for a food tax to effectively influence behavior,
the increase in price needs to be at least 20% (Mytton, Clarke, & Rayner, 2012; Cornelsen, Green, Dangour, & Smith, 2014). Unhealthy foods are so inexpensive that they
will still be relatively cheaper after taxing, compared to healthy products. You
can choose to spend €3 on a smoked salmon and lettuce sandwich in the
supermarket, but for that same money you can get yourself a package of
chocolate chip cookies, a large bag of crisps and a can of Coke. The tax
revenue should therefore be used to promote or subsidize healthy food to
stimulate its consumption. Unfortunately, the resulting outcome is not as
straightforward as it might seem. Behavioral economics has persistently shown
that ‘losses weigh more than gains’ and that people’s negative reaction to
taxes will be stronger than their positive reaction to subsidies, thereby
rendering subsidies to increase healthy food consumption less effective than
expected (Cornelsen et al., 2014).
Moreover,
data representing the effects of food taxes on food consumption focuses on the reduction
in consumption of the targeted product(s). This leaves out any changes in
behavior regarding other products, which might be consumed as a substitute (Epstein et al., 2012). While
the numbers might demonstrate a reduction in the quantity of consumed soft
drinks at a fast food restaurant, the number of consumers who buy a dessert
instead is neglected.
Although
taxes are supposed to influence all levels of the population equally, a fat tax
will most likely target the wallet of poor people since they spend a bigger
proportion of their income on food (Mytton
et al., 2012; Cornelsen et al., 2014). Then again, the people belonging to this part
of the population are the ones who will most benefit from a fat tax since they
are the ones that consume more unhealthy products and are more at risk of
becoming obese. However, the income
effect shows that people, especially those of low socioeconomic status, will
continue to buy the more expensive, taxed food, but will reduce the amount
spend on other, healthier food (Cornelsen et al., 2014). An increase in price
might therefore not necessarily make us give up our favorite and habitual foods,
especially if they serve as ‘comfort foods’ that alleviate discomfort in
stressful situations.
A
last but important point to be made is that although taxing food might have
unpredictable results and not have the desired health effect, the revenue
gained opens new doors. A review by Capacci et al. (2012) on public policies
used to promote healthy eating, shows that whereas the fat tax seems to only
have a weak effect on changing behavior, it does yield a lot of tax revenue. For instance, California’s tax on soft drinks generates
around $218 million a year. Thus the fat tax is an effective way to create
profit that can then be used to subsidize or promote healthy food. Nevertheless,
as the effect of taxes and subsidies are not as clear-cut due to the relative
weight of gains and losses, as well as the availability of alternative products
and rigid food preferences, Belgium should think twice before implementing a
fat tax. Taking Denmark’s failed tax on saturated fats due to cross-border
trading as an example, we should thoroughly consider the various influences a
fat tax can have on human behavior. The behavior of consumers is highly
dependent on price changes, but without also investing resources in public
awareness and nutritional education, the resulting change in people’s diets will
be limited.
Almudena Claassen is a Ph.D. student at the Université
Libre de Bruxelles. She is currently working on the FOOD4GUT project.
References
Capacci, S., Mazzocchi, M., Shankar,
B., Brambila Macias, J., Verbeke, W., Pérez‐Cueto, F. J., ... & Traill,
W. B. (2012). Policies to promote healthy eating in Europe: a structured review
of policies and their effectiveness. Nutrition Reviews, 70,
188-200. doi: 10.1111/j.1753-4887.2011.00442.x
Cornelsen, L., Green, R., Dangour, A., &
Smith, R. (2014). Why fat taxes won't make us thin. Journal of Public Health,
1-6. doi: 10.1093/pubmed/fdu032
Eckert, M. (2014, September 22).
Onderzoek UGent toont aan: ‘Tijd dat Belgie vettaks invoert’. De Standaard. Retrieved from:
http://www.standaard.be/cnt/dmf20140921_01280328
Epstein, L.H., Jankowiak, N.,
Nederkoorn, C., Raynor, H.A., French, S.A.. & Finkelstein, E. (2012).
Experimental research on the relation between food price changes and
food-purchasing patterns: a targeted review. The American Journal of Clinical Nutrition, 95, 789-809. doi:
10.3945/ajcn.111.024380
European Society of Cardiology. (2014).
Adult obesity predicted in almost all European countries by 2030. Science Daily. Retrieved from: www.sciencedaily.com/releases/2014/05/140509110711.htm
Eurostat. (2011). Overweight and obesity – BMI statistics. Retrieved from:
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/statistics_explained/index.php/Overweight_and_obesity_-_BMI_statistics
Finkelstein, E. A., Khavjou, O. A.,
Thompson, H., Trogdon, J. G., Pan, L., Sherry, B., & Dietz, W. (2012).
Obesity and severe obesity forecasts through 2030. American Journal of
Preventive Medicine, 42, 563-570. doi: 10.1016/j.amepre.2011.10.026
Mytton, O. T., Clarke, D., &
Rayner, M. (2012). Taxing unhealthy food and drinks to improve health. BMJ,
344, 1-7. doi:
10.1136/bmj.e2931
there have wonderful article many faces of the Fat Tax to discuss affairs harmful tax competition in the Code of conduct on business taxation. really informative post.
ReplyDeleteHire Tax advisers in the UK | Is a trust tax avoidance
it is seem to be very essential blog to discuss about the topic of The many faces of the Fat Tax. thanks for share useful info of research shows that for a food tax to effectively influence behavior, the increase in price.
ReplyDeletePay less tax in the UK
Property tax planning in the UK
I’ve been your silent reader for quite some time and now I’m delighted to say that I’m inspired by your articles. You have shared very valuable information and knowledge that people should recognise. Thank you for sharing. I would love to see more updates from you.
ReplyDeleteTax Advisor